The sky’s the limit: The economics of inflation and hyperinflation

7 Hyperinflation

Hyperinflation is defined as a rate of inflation of at least 50% per month that lasts more than two months. It is a relatively modern phenomenon: the first recorded case was in France in 1795–1796, during the French Revolution, but the vast majority of cases have happened since the beginning of the twentieth century. There were eight cases across seven countries between 1920 and 1946, none between 1947 and 1984, and 18 cases across 16 countries between 1985 and 2024.1

Under hyperinflation, domestic currency loses its function as money.

Recall the three uses of money (Section 1): as a store of value, as a unit of account, and as a means of exchange. When inflation reaches excessive levels then all three of these roles are compromised.

Domestic currency loses its role as a store of value for the obvious reason that it buys less and less, declining at an alarming rate. Moreover, this applies not just to cash but also to bonds denominated in domestic currency: their nominal interest rate can fall far behind inflation, implying that their real value collapses. For this reason, people no longer want to hold on to assets denominated in domestic currency. Instead, people will try to hold alternatives like ‘hard currency’, meaning some currency that tends to retain its value over time—most often US dollars because of their availability and universal acceptance.

Money under hyperinflation loses its role as a unit of account for the same reason: today the unit means something very different from tomorrow or next week. The problem is exacerbated by the fact that very high inflation also tends to be very variable. If inflation was 15% last month then it might easily be 10%, or 30%, this month. That makes it very difficult for firms to know by how much they should raise their own prices, leading to mispricing, or the situation where prices no longer reflect relative scarcity. Recall that the efficient allocation of goods via markets depends on prices reflecting relative scarcity. When many goods are mispriced, markets fail to clear: goods fail to sell, or they sell out very quickly.

Various strategies arise to address this problem. Dollarization is one common approach. This means that people start using dollars instead of domestic currency, whether for everyday transactions or for saving. Another is to use some commodity as a reference. For example, one parents’ group at a primary school in Argentina had an arrangement whereby when a child in the class had a birthday, instead of every family buying a small present, families would take turns buying a single large present on behalf of the class. In order to ensure that the presents retained the same value over time they agreed that it should cost the same as 100 litres of petrol (which ranged between about USD75 and USD100).

Finally, under extremely high inflation, domestic currency loses its effectiveness as a means of exchange. Seeing prices rise every week, every day, or even several times per day, leads people to buy goods as quickly as they can. The Argentine economist Mercedes d’Alessandro, who was a child during the hyperinflation episodes of 1989–1990, records her and her friends’ experiences of hunting for goods in the supermarket whose prices had not yet been updated that day. Families would stock up on spaghetti as soon as their wages came in, knowing that the next day it would be more expensive. One witness recalls seeing someone buying four table fans at the supermarket because that’s what there was: ‘people bought whatever they could … They didn’t know what to spend their money on. Holding onto it made no sense.’2

As D’Alessandro notes, when domestic currency loses its function as money, people no longer want to hold onto it. They do not want to save in it, and when they want to spend, they spend it as fast as they can. This leads to a collapse in what is often called ‘money demand’: the demand people have to hold domestic currency. This is a somewhat misleading term for two reasons. First, people still want money—what they don’t want is domestic currency, precisely because it has lost its role as money. Instead, demand for alternative forms of money like US dollars will increase as demand for domestic currency falls. Second, it is not just domestic cash that people don’t want to hold—demand may collapse for any financial asset denominated in domestic currency if expected inflation is higher than the nominal interest rate. But declining money demand, when understood as demand for domestic currency, is fundamental to explaining hyperinflation.

The mechanisms sustaining hyperinflation

Before we examine how hyperinflation episodes begin, we identify a set of mechanisms that explain why hyperinflation is self-reinforcing, and why it is so difficult to halt once it takes off.

The first three mechanisms are related to the collapse in demand for domestic currency that we have just described.

First, the desire to spend currency as quickly as possible pushes up nominal aggregate demand. This signals to firms that they can keep raising prices.

Second, the desire to exchange domestic currency for dollars pushes up the demand for dollars relative to domestic currency, implying a depreciation or devaluation. This fuels the depreciation–inflation or devaluation–inflation spiral we analysed above.

The third mechanism involves the dynamics of seigniorage and money printing. Section 6 showed that governments print money both in order to cover a fiscal deficit and in response to rising demand for base money due to rising nominal GDP. Under hyperinflation, nominal GDP is multiplying quickly, and the government is printing money at a very rapid rate. But at a certain point prices tend to rise faster than the government is printing money, implying that real seigniorage revenue falls even as money printing accelerates. Using the seigniorage equation \(\text{seigniorage} = \frac{\mathrm{\Delta}M}{M} \times \frac{M}{P}\), if \(P\) rises faster than \(\mathrm{\Delta}M\), then real seigniorage is falling. This is why seigniorage does not just rise with inflation. For example, in Figure 8, seigniorage peaked in Bolivia in 1984 when inflation was nearly 1,300%, and seigniorage fell in 1985 when inflation exploded to over 117,000%.

Another way to understand the third mechanism is to recall that seigniorage is driven by the inflation tax (setting aside the small amount of seigniorage due to real growth), and that this is a tax on holdings of domestic currency and domestic bonds. When demand for domestic currency falls, people are holding less real currency. This means the base for the inflation tax falls in real terms, and any given level of inflation will yield less seigniorage revenue in real terms. If the government cannot close its fiscal deficit or borrow to reduce the amount of real revenue that it needs, then it will need an ever-higher rate of inflation on a shrinking real monetary base, leading to accelerations in both money printing and prices.

There are three other key mechanisms that sustain hyperinflation.

First, more frequent wage bargaining leads to higher inflation, as discussed in Section 2. This occurs as inflation gets higher because workers see their real wages deteriorating more rapidly, and demand more frequent adjustments. This might involve frequent indexing, or automatic upgrading of contracts including wages, which can cause very rapid price acceleration.

Second, under high and rising inflation, any inflation target or other nominal anchor becomes highly implausible: people know that it won’t be achieved. Expectations become ‘unanchored’. As inflation begins to rise, expectations might become adaptive. But as inflation rises further and people notice that inflation at time \(t\) tends to be even higher than inflation at time \(t - 1\), inflation expectations might even exceed the previous period’s actual inflation rate. As in the example of Luciana’s ice cream shop in Argentina (Section 1), sometimes expectations become anchored to the price of the dollar: if the dollar rises by 10% this month, then everyone assumes inflation will be 10%, and raises their own prices accordingly. This also implies that a real devaluation is impossible—every depreciation is followed by an equal rise in prices, so that the real exchange rate does not depreciate, guaranteeing that the depreciation–inflation spiral will continue, as discussed in Section 4.

Third, real tax revenues are likely to collapse because of the ‘Olivera–Tanzi effect’,3 4 discovered by the Argentine economist Julio H. G. Olivera and later elaborated by the IMF economist Vito Tanzi. This refers to the fact that tax revenue tends to be charged retrospectively (after the taxed transaction occurs). Value added taxes may be transferred to the government 30 or 60 days after the relevant transaction. Personal income taxes are often calculated at the end of the tax year. But under hyperinflation, waiting a month, let alone a year, will slash the real value of the tax by the time the government receives it. This worsens the fiscal deficit, further increasing the pressure to print money to raise seigniorage revenue.

The path to hyperinflation

These mechanisms explain why high inflation can be self-sustaining and lead to rising inflation and hyperinflation. We now ask what can kick-start this process.

The most immediate driver of hyperinflation is typically a combination of an unmanageable fiscal deficit leading to high levels of money printing, and a depreciation–inflation spiral (or its fixed exchange rate equivalent, the devaluation–inflation spiral). But more important is the underlying cause of the fiscal deficit. In cases like the French Revolution or the US Civil War, it was due to the need to increase expenditure to finance the conflict, combined with grave constraints on tax collection: in the absence of effective infrastructure, conflict makes it very difficult for the state to collect taxes from its citizens.

Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation from 2007 on was driven by poorly executed land reforms in the 1990s that led to a collapse in food production. This caused a general decline in output, and hence a decline in government revenue. Foreign debt soon began to play a role as well: exports dropped from USD3.2 billion in 1997 to USD1.9 billion in 2003, causing a rise in the current account deficit, which led to rising foreign debt, and further rises in debt payments. This exacerbated the fiscal deficit, the need for the government to acquire dollars, devaluations, and the pressure to print money.

In many cases, foreign debt has been the primary driver of hyperinflation episodes. The 1922–1923 hyperinflation episode in Germany was caused by an excessive debt burden of what Germany owed to the victors of World War I; the multiple hyperinflation episodes in Latin American countries in the 1980s and early 1990s were the result of the debt crisis that began around 1980. In this crisis, unsustainable foreign debt led to very high inflation or hyperinflation through the two mechanisms discussed: high debt payments led to loss of reserves that drove devaluation–inflation spirals, and to fiscal deficits that could be financed only by printing money. We now examine this episode in detail.

The 1980s debt crisis

The 1980s debt crisis was caused by two key developments. First, in the 1970s many low- and middle-income countries took out debt in foreign currency (dollars), borrowing from international banks. They did so because the international interest rate was relatively low and, encouraged by the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, they believed this borrowing would enable them to reduce poverty, increase investment, and raise their growth rates.

Second, in 1979 the US Federal Reserve started increasing interest rates to unprecedented levels in response to high inflation in the US. The federal funds rate rose from around 5% in the mid-1970s to 15% at the beginning of 1980, reaching 16.4% in 1981.

Average spending on education in OECD countries was about 4.8% in the 1980s, according to World Bank data.

While US policymakers were motivated by the domestic effect of this rise, it had enormous international implications. Most of the international debt issued in the 1970s had interest rates linked to international rates, so when the largest economy in the world increased its own interest rate, these rates jumped alongside it. Figure 9 shows the spike in debt repayments that this caused for countries in low- and middle-income regions. The spike was particularly dramatic in Latin America, where debt repayments jumped from around 1% of GNI in the mid-1970s to over 5% in the early 1980s. For comparison, this was more than average spending on education in OECD countries.

The first clear indication of crisis was in August 1982, when Mexico became the first country to declare that it could not meet its debt repayment obligations. It was forced to devalue, with the exchange rate (the price of dollars in pesos) more than doubling. By the end of the year approximately 40 countries had fallen into arrears. But while they could not meet all their debt obligations, ongoing payments remained high enough to cause large current account and fiscal deficits, a situation that continued through the 1980s.

Figure 10 presents Mexico’s interest payments and fiscal deficit as shares of GDP, and the level of inflation. All three variables are very closely correlated, rising dramatically at the beginning of the 1980s. In 1982 inflation jumped to 59% as interest payments rose to 4.3% of GNI and the fiscal deficit reached 10.8% of GDP. Both inflation and interest payments reached their peaks in 1987, with inflation reaching 132% and interest payments 18.3% of GNI, while the fiscal deficit was 13.5%.

What does this mean for the government’s accounts? The primary fiscal balance is defined as what the fiscal balance would be excluding debt payments. So it is equal to government revenue minus government expenditure on goods and services (including salaries of public employees, public investment, and so on). Thus in 1982 with a fiscal deficit of 10.8% and interest payments of 4.3%, there was a primary deficit of \(10.8 \: – \: 4.3 = 6.5\%\). By 1987, after a great deal of fiscal tightening, the primary balance was actually in surplus, at \(18.3\% \: – \: 13.5 = 4.8\%\). It was the debt payments of 18.3% of GDP that pushed the overall fiscal balance negative.

The devaluation–inflation spiral was also severe, with the exchange rate continuing a rapid rise until 1988. From 1981 to 1990 prices had risen by a factor of 117 and the exchange rate by a factor of 115.

Line chart showing interest payments on external debt as a percentage of GNI from 1970 to 2022 for East Asia and Pacific, Latin America and Caribbean, and sub-Saharan Africa. Latin America peaks above 5% in the 1980s, while the other regions stay below 3% over the whole period shown. All series decline after the 1990s, though Latin America remains the highest. Following the global financial crisis, all regions show a slight increase.
Fullscreen
https://books.core-econ.org/insights/economics-of-inflation-and-hyperinflation/07-hyperinflation.html#figure-9

Figure 9 Interest payments on external debt as % of GNI (1970–2022).

World Bank. 2024. Interest payments on external debt (% of GNI). World Development Indicators.

Three lines show Mexico’s fiscal deficit (as a percentage of GDP), interest payments (as a percentage of GNI), and inflation rate (as a percentage), over the years 1975 to 2000. All three indicators rise sharply throughout the 1980s, with inflation peaking above 100% around 1987. All indicators declined steeply after 1988 and remain relatively lower through to 2000.
Fullscreen
https://books.core-econ.org/insights/economics-of-inflation-and-hyperinflation/07-hyperinflation.html#figure-10

Figure 10 Interest payments, the fiscal deficit, and inflation in Mexico (1975–2000).

World Bank. 2024. Interest payments on external debt (% of GNI). World Development Indicators.

Some other countries fared even worse. Argentina (1989–1990), Bolivia (1984–1985), Brazil (1989–1990), and Nicaragua (1986–1991) all suffered hyperinflation episodes, lasting between four months and nearly five years, while many other countries experienced very high inflation for long periods.

The debt crisis was finally stabilized around 1990. In Figure 10 the decline in all three variables occurred after several years of failed debt negotiations culminated in the successful plan of Nicholas Brady, US Secretary of the Treasury. In this plan, debtor countries and creditor banks agreed to a substantial debt restructuring, amounting to an overall debt reduction of about 32% for 18 debtor countries.5 At the same time, governments, under pressure from creditor countries and international organizations like the IMF, privatized (sold) many public firms in order to raise money to pay off part of their stock of debt. This reduced the depth of restructuring required, meaning that it reduced the losses that creditors had to incur.

Question 7 Choose the correct answer(s)

Read the following statements about the mechanisms causing hyperinflation and select the correct option(s).

  • As inflation rises, people seek to exchange domestic currency for foreign currency, which fuels depreciation and worsens inflation.
  • Under hyperinflation, governments can stabilize seigniorage revenue by printing money at a steady rate.
  • The Olivera–Tanzi effect worsens the fiscal deficit during hyperinflation by reducing the real value of tax revenues collected.
  • Hyperinflation is typically triggered by an external supply shock, such as an oil price increase, which alone is enough to sustain high inflation indefinitely.
  • A declining demand for domestic currency leads to depreciation, raising import prices and fuelling the depreciation–inflation spiral.
  • Seigniorage revenue does not increase indefinitely with money printing. As prices rise faster than money creation, real seigniorage revenue falls, worsening the fiscal crisis.
  • Since taxes are often collected after transactions occur, inflation erodes their real value before the government receives them, exacerbating the fiscal deficit.
  • While supply shocks can contribute to inflation, the proximate cause of hyperinflation is typically a combination of an unmanageable fiscal deficit leading to high levels of money printing, and a depreciation–inflation spiral.

Escaping from hyperinflation: Adjustment and the nominal anchor

The restructuring of foreign debt was a necessary condition for cutting inflation. But it was not sufficient. First, cuts in spending and tax rises were needed in order to bring down the primary fiscal deficit (the fiscal deficit excluding debt repayments). (Mexico had already achieved a primary surplus by 1983.)

Second, governments needed to anchor expectations to a lower level of inflation. If people continue to expect 20% or 50% inflation per month, then it is extremely difficult to avoid writing contracts that fulfil this expectation. One way to do this is to implement a fixed exchange rate, where the government commits to exchange domestic currency for dollars at a fixed price. As discussed in Section 2, this can stabilize the prices of tradable goods via competition with imports, preventing firms from raising their prices. It will also break the depreciation–inflation spiral.

However, a new fixed exchange needs to be credible: the population must believe it is sustainable. If people do not believe the new fixed exchange rate is sustainable then they will sell domestic currency for dollars in anticipation of a devaluation. The government will lose reserves in the process, until the devaluation becomes inevitable, fulfilling the prediction and reigniting the devaluation–inflation spiral. For this reason, debt restructuring and the reduction in the fiscal deficit must make the new currency peg look sustainable, and interest rates must be maintained at a high enough level to maintain demand for the currency—saving in domestic currency (buying domestic currency bonds) has to become sufficiently attractive that people no longer want to save only in dollars.

One important risk for exchange rate-based programmes is that if the exchange rate is fixed but inflation does not come down quickly, then the rising price level implies an appreciating real exchange rate. As discussed in Section 4, this implies a decline in competitiveness and a rising current account deficit, causing the fixed exchange rate to become unsustainable. Thus a fixed exchange rate can be part of a stabilization programme, but is not sufficient on its own.

A new inflation target may also be implemented. But such a target tends not to be credible in a country with a history of high inflation if it is not also connected to a credible fixed exchange rate. A commitment to constrain the amount of base money that the government prints can also feature but, as discussed in Section 5, money printing is endogenous: it occurs automatically when nominal GDP grows. This means that inflation causes money printing as well as the other way around. So it too is unlikely to be credible in the absence of other complementary measures.

In addition to fiscal tightening and a nominal anchor to fix inflation expectations, a variety of other policies are sometimes implemented to help cut through the inflationary cycles, particularly policies to coordinate wage- and price-setting, such as the elimination of indexing of contracts.

The good news is that when all the other mechanisms have been interrupted, disinflation through recession (pushing unemployment above the supply-side equilibrium) may not be necessary. This is consistent with our original model: once expectations are brought down and anchored, the Phillips curve automatically shifts downwards. For this reason, effective stabilizations can lead to a rapid reactivation of the economy. In the ‘Find out more’ box below, we discuss the combination of policies that Brazil used to escape from hyperinflation. Once it had implemented the plan, the economy quickly returned to economic growth.

Find out more Brazil’s Real Plan

This ‘Find out more’ box is based on the Harvard Business School case Brazil: The Real Plan (A) UV1618; João Ayres, Marcio Garcia, Diogo Guillen, and Patrick Kehoe. (2019). ‘The Monetary and Fiscal History of Brazil, 1960–2016’, IDB Working Paper Series IDB-WP-990; and data from the World Bank and the Central Bank of Brazil.

Brazil was hit hard by the rise in US interest rates of 1979–1980. After accumulating debt at low rates in the 1970s, its debt service jumped to 7% of GNI in 1981 as the US interest rate surpassed 16%. It devalued, doubling the exchange rate from 1980 to 1981 and doubling it again in 1982, and by 1985 it had grown by a factor of 160. After a redenomination of the currency in 1986, the exchange rate nearly quintupled in 1987 and multiplied more than ten times in 1988.

At the same time, unable to raise sufficient revenue via taxes, and unable to borrow more because of its existing levels of debt, the government resorted to printing money to cover its resulting fiscal deficit. Driven by the combination of the devaluation–inflation spiral and monetary financing of the fiscal deficit, annual inflation rose above 100% in late 1981 and above 200% in 1986, and accelerated to hyperinflationary levels (above 50% per month) from December 1989 to March 1990. While the hyperinflation was temporary, monthly inflation remained between 20 and 40% until 1994.

Various stabilization plans were attempted from 1986 onwards. The currency was redenominated in 1986, 1989, and 1993, each time losing three zeros and receiving a new name. Attempts were made to reduce the fiscal deficit, with limited success. Wage and price freezes were attempted multiple times, which sometimes worked temporarily but never lasted. They were ineffective because they did not address the underlying pressures behind the wage–price spiral: if the wage and price freeze came into effect shortly after a wage rise, then firms would find their profits reduced, sometimes even making a loss, and goods would run out, leading to shortages. If it came into effect shortly after a series of price rises, then workers would find their real wages distressingly low, and would agitate for a wage rise.

The stabilization plan that finally worked was called the Real Plan, starting in June 1993, a month after President Itamar Franco appointed Fernando Henrique Cardoso as Minister of Finance. As we will see, the success of the plan (and the failures of its predecessors) can be explained using the models and mechanisms in this Insight.

When Cardoso became Minister of Finance, inflation over the preceding 12 months had been more than 1,300% and the economy was in recession. In its favour, Brazil’s international debts had just been renegotiated as part of the US-led Brady Plan, which covered many highly indebted countries. This meant that creditors had accepted a reduction in the amount they were owed to a level that Brazil could afford to pay, reducing its debt payments and allowing it to return to international capital markets for new international borrowing. In addition, the previous stabilization attempt had prepared the ground by cutting public expenditures, opening the economy to increase international competition, and privatizing numerous public enterprises.

In preparation for the Real Plan the government started by cutting expenditure further and raising existing taxes such as the income tax, and creating new taxes, including a tax on financial transactions. These unpopular measures were justified on the basis of economic emergency. The goal was to be ready when seigniorage revenues declined in anticipation of falling inflation. In addition, constraints on the issuing of base money led to a rise in interest rates.

The most controversial part of the plan was the creation of a new virtual currency called the URV or unidade real de valor (unit of real value). No notes were issued in this new currency, so it was neither a store of value nor a means of exchange. Instead it was purely a unit of account. It was declared that one URV was equal to one US dollar, so the exchange rate between the actual currency, the cruzeiro real (CR), and the URV would vary along with the dollar exchange rate. The URV was launched with the official launch of the Real Plan in February 1994, and from 1 March prices had to be quoted in both CR and in URV.

Every transaction would still be made in cruzeiros reais (the plural of ‘real’), but the price in URV would be quoted at the same time. On 1 March 1994 the URV was worth CR647.50, so a car might cost URV10,000 and CR6,475,000. That month, inflation in the CR was running at over 1% per day, meaning that the following week the price in CR would be 10% higher. But the price in URVs remained much more stable. The idea was that people would see the URV maintaining its value over time, so that they would expect very low inflation in this new currency. The government encouraged people to write contracts in URV, which they were happy to do because of its visible stability.

In May the government announced that the URV would become the new currency and would be known simply as the real or R$. After just 18 weeks of life, the URV was eliminated on 1 July 1994, and the real was set equal to one dollar, which at that moment was worth CR2,750. The population had become used to the idea of a stable URV or real, so when it became the actual currency they maintained low inflation expectations.

At the same time, the government set an upper limit of the exchange rate at one dollar, meaning the real would be allowed to appreciate, but not depreciate. Thus the dollar provided an ongoing price anchor for the new currency.

The plan was a success. In August, monthly inflation was below 2%; in 1995 the annual inflation rate was 22%, the lowest it had been in 20 years. Inflation continued to decline over the following years and it has rarely exceeded 10% since.

After multiple failed stabilization plans, the Real Plan worked because of the combination of its different elements. The fiscal and monetary tightening were necessary because the economy had to be close to the supply-side equilibrium to avoid continuing wage–price spirals. The renegotiation of foreign debt was also essential both in order to achieve deficit reduction and to avoid continuing devaluations.

But these measures on their own would not have been sufficient because years of high inflation had established extremely high inflation expectations. In our model, this means that the Phillips curve was very elevated, so inflation would remain very high even at the supply-side equilibrium. It was necessary to address those inflation expectations directly, and that is what the URV achieved. Fixing the exchange rate to the dollar in a context of relative openness helped maintain those low inflation expectations over time. And that exchange rate in turn was credible only because the real interest rate was sufficiently positive to make real-denominated bonds look attractive.

Question 8 Choose the correct answer(s)

Read the following statements about how to escape hyperinflation, and select the correct option(s).

  • Cutting the fiscal deficit is a necessary but insufficient step to ending hyperinflation.
  • A successful stabilization plan must anchor inflation expectations, often by fixing the exchange rate or adopting an inflation target.
  • Fixing the domestic currency to the US dollar eliminates the risk of inflation, as this guarantees price stability.
  • A new fixed exchange rate must be credible, or people will anticipate devaluation, leading to reserve losses that make the devaluation inevitable.
  • While reducing the fiscal deficit is essential, it alone will not stop hyperinflation unless expectations are also stabilized.
  • If expectations remain unanchored, inflation may persist even if fiscal and monetary policies are tightened.
  • While dollarization or a currency peg can help stabilize inflation, it does not remove all risks.
  • If the public doubts the peg’s sustainability, they will sell domestic currency for dollars, forcing the government to burn reserves until devaluation becomes inevitable.

Exercise 7 Brazil’s fiscal deficit

Brazil’s fiscal deficit (denoted as net lending (a positive number) divided by net borrowing (a negative number), expressed as a percentage of GDP) since 2010 can be plotted using the World Bank’s databank.

Its real interest rate can be plotted at this World Bank webpage.

Compare these with the equivalent series for South Africa by typing ‘South Africa’ into the box at the top of the webpage. Both countries have had sustained inflation of below 10% since 2010 in an inflation-targeting regime. Suggest some explanations for the differences in the real interest rate in Brazil compared to South Africa.

Exercise 8 Ending a hyperinflation episode

Is cutting the fiscal deficit sufficient to end a hyperinflation episode? Explain why or why not.

  1. Stanley Fischer, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Végh. 2002. ‘Modern Hyper- and High Inflations’. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(3): pp. 837–880. 

  2. Mercedes D’Alessandro. 2024. Motosierra y confusión: Cómo recuperar la economía para salir de la crisis. Buenos Aires: Sudamericana: pp. 96. 

  3. Julio H. G. Olivera. 1967. ‘Money, prices and fiscal lags: A note on the dynamics of inflation’. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review 20(82), pp. 258–267. 

  4. Vito Tanzi. 1992. ‘Fiscal policy and economic reconstruction in Latin America’. World Development 20(5), pp. 641–657. 

  5. Timothy J. Curry. 1997. ‘The LDC Debt Crisis’. In History of the Eighties – Lessons for the Future: An Examination of the Banking Crises of the 1980s and Early 1990s, Vol. 1, pp. 191–210. Washington: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.